CHAPTER 68 Managed Care and Psychiatry
OVERVIEW
—Noted economist Ariel Rubinstein, upon the awarding of the Nobel Prize to the economist John Nash in 19941
THE HISTORY OF MENTAL HEALTH CARE FINANCE IN THE UNITED STATES
Throughout the history of the United States, social movements relating to the care of the mentally ill have altered the delivery and financing of MHC3 (Table 68-1). After the Revolutionary War, increasing urbanization led to the development of asylums for the mentally ill, most notably in Philadelphia (Pennsylvania) and Williamsburg (Virginia). Before the establishment of these state-run, state-financed psychiatric hospitals, local communities and families bore the brunt of the responsibility for caring for the mentally ill, initially through local almshouses (poorhouses) and then through more formalized financing methods. As the financial burden on localities increased over time, an effort was made to shift the costs of financing MHC to the states. A corollary goal supported by the psychiatric profession involved separating the financing of care for the mentally ill from local, charity-based indigent care.
A group of reformers (led by Horace Mann, among others) led the “moral treatment” movement, which advocated for the institutionalization of patients with the hopes that early treatment would lead to a resolution of their mental illness. The activist Dorthea Dix, in particular, was instrumental in lobbying state legislatures for the establishment of psychiatric hospitals. Eventually, each state developed its own asylum system in response to the movement. Over the course of the nineteenth century, asylums became overcrowded, and, as the promise of early intervention went largely unfulfilled, asylums became the permanent home to many chronically ill patients. Funding of asylums did not increase with the rise in the patient population. State and local governments were in conflict as to how to fund mental health services, with the latter often choosing to place the mentally ill in jail or in almshouses rather than pay for care at asylums.4 In the latter half of the nineteenth century, a new movement known as the “mental hygiene” movement sought to improve the conditions of patients in asylums. A number of federal laws, known as the State Care Acts, required states to pay for all asylum care, prompting localities to send an ever-increasing number of patients to asylums. Reformers from the National Committee on Mental Hygiene also advocated for treatment of mental illness in medical hospitals, as well as in outpatient settings, bringing MHC more into the medical model of care. This continued to be the case into the 1930s when a new method of private employer–based health insurance financing was born.5
THE RISE OF PRIVATE HEALTH INSURANCE
The current system of employer-based health insurance, while accidental in its conception, has become entrenched as the primary way by which health care is financed in this country. Until the 1930s, private individuals paid out-of-pocket for health care services on a fee-for-service basis.6 During the 1930s, nonprofit Blue Cross/Blue Shield (BCBS) health insurance plans were developed and, despite skepticism as to their viability, were successful. Once health insurance was shown by the BCBS plans to be a financially feasible endeavor, a number of private for-profit health insurance companies were founded. During World War II, when the government allowed employers to offer health insurance in lieu of wage increases, private health insurers grew in both size and number, with the number of covered individuals rising from 20.6 million to 142 million between 1940 and 1950.6 Coverage expanded even further and became more tightly linked to employment contracts when, in 1954, the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) ruled that employer-based health insurance should not be considered as taxable income. While coverage was expanded for general medical care, MHC coverage was substantially more limited. Insurance policies did not include mental health services until after World War II, when insurers began covering some hospital-based psychiatric care. Before the deinstitutionalization movement (discussed in the next section), there was little incentive for private insurers to cover services that were already paid for through the public sector.7
THE COMMUNITY MENTAL HEALTH CENTER MOVEMENT AND DEINSTITUTIONALIZATION
In the 1950s, a third movement in United States MHC began, referred to as the Community Mental Health Center Movement. It was founded on the belief that, with the advent of new and improved pharmacological and somatic treatments, MHC was best delivered in the community. Movement advocates pointed to continued poor conditions in asylums as evidence that deinstitutionalization of patients would best serve their interests.5 Federal legislation in the early 1960s targeted federal funds for the development of community mental health centers (CMHCs) across the country. According to historian Gerald Grob, the deinstitutionalization of patients was not simply an en masse exodus from mental hospitals to the community, but rather a shift in emphasis from long-term care to management of more acute episodes, driven by the expansion of outpatient services through CMHCs.5
During this time, funding for MHC services became more complex. Services (such as medical care housing and meals that were at one time contained in mental hospitals) were no longer provided within a single context. Federal programs (such as the Social Security Disability Insurance [SSDI] program) would become increasingly important for providing financial support to the chronically mentally ill. Additionally, new public health insurance programs in the 1960s would further change the way MHC was financed.
INSURING MENTAL HEALTH CARE: MORAL HAZARD, ADVERSE SELECTION, AND THE RISE OF MANAGED BEHAVIORAL CARVE-OUTS
With the provision of MHC increasingly financed by public and private insurance plans over the latter half of the twentieth century, economic problems inherent in the structure of the health care market became increasingly evident. From the mid-1960s until the early 1990s, health costs increased by an annual rate of 4.1%8 compared with a 1.5% increase in the gross domestic product (GDP). Such a rise was believed to be largely due to both a rise in technological advances, such as new drugs and devices and a health insurance market that was ineffective and inefficient at rationing care (with the latter allowing ever-increasing usage and total costs brought on in part by the former). In order to understand the rise of managed care plans and their impact on mental health, it is crucial to understand the “basic science” of health insurance that leads to difficulties with financing care.